The demand for private health insurance: do waiting lists matter?

https://doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(98)00108-XGet rights and content

Abstract

In spite of government dominance in financing health care in many countries, the private health care sector remains important. This is true even though most public provision is heavily subsidized, and in many cases free, at source. Britain's National Health Service fails to drive out the private sector because it suffers from certain inflexibilities. Here, we show that longer waiting lists for NHS treatment are associated with greater purchases of private health insurance.

Introduction

In most developed countries of the world, government is the dominant financier of health care. Yet still the private sector remains an important force. This is true in spite of heavily subsidized, and in many cases free, public provision. Perhaps the principal reason why government provision fails to drive out the private sector completely is that it is generally less flexible in catering to the diversity of tastes in the population than a market allocation. That is not to argue that there are not good equity and efficiency reasons for government provision, just that it comes at a cost. Hence, some individuals will regard it as worthwhile to pay for health care, foregoing free public sector provision, in order to get their exact treatment requirements.1 For the most part, these individuals purchase insurance to smooth their medical payments.

This paper explores one dimension of this using evidence from the UK. Within the UK, the National Health Service (NHS) remains the dominant provider of health care and insurance, with provision that is basically free at source. Yet some 14–17% of the population voluntarily purchase supplementary private insurance. We look for evidence that this is motivated by the inflexibilities of the public sector. Chief among these, which have figured greatly in popular discussions, are waiting lists for NHS treatment. An individual who needs a non-urgent medical intervention is often placed on a waiting list prior to seeing a consultant or to receiving treatment. Economic theory predicts that private insurance purchases should be sensitive to such concerns since, in the private sector, individuals can guarantee themselves instant access to treatment when necessary.2 Furthermore, the privately insured also gain access to certain `hotel benefits' such as better food and private rooms.

We study the demand for private health insurance using data from the British Social Attitudes (BSA) survey, a nationally representative annual survey of some 3000 individuals. The questions on health that we use were collected in five years of the data (1986, 1987, 1989, 1990 and 1991). Individuals are matched with data on the NHS from Regional Trends, by identifying which regional health authority each respondent lives in. We estimate a model of the demand for individually purchased private health insurance, which is allowed to depend upon information about NHS service provision. Here, we exploit the regional organization of the NHS to get both cross-sectional and time series variation in our measures of NHS performance. We show that increases in long-term NHS waiting lists are linked to increases in private health insurance purchases. We also relate insurance demand to a host of individual and household characteristics, showing that a typical individual with private medical insurance is relatively well-off, middle-aged and a supporter of the Conservative party.3

The analysis of this paper relates to a large existing literature on government programs. Our principal finding that waiting lists affect private insurance demand is consonant with the literature on rationing by waiting (see, for example, Nicholls et al., 1971Barzel, 1974Deacon and Sonstelie, 1989). Since the NHS is essentially free at source, such models argue that queuing may serve as a rationing device. In particular, Lindsay and Feigenbaum (1984) makes this observation explicitly about NHS waiting lists. Our analysis emphasises that individuals face an opportunity to avoid public sector waiting by purchasing private health insurance. Empirical evidence on the relevance of these kinds of models is relatively rare (Deacon and Sonstelie, 1985, being a key exception). This paper provides further evidence.

The literature has also observed that rationing by waiting is a pure deadweight loss unless there is some gain in terms of targeting resources to a particular socially favoured group. Here, we show that low income individuals are least likely to exit the queue by purchasing private insurance, which empirically confirms the pro-poor bias that has previously been suggested as a consequence of rationing by waiting.

Our paper emphasises the importance of viewing the public provision of private goods in a market context. In Stiglitz (1974), Sonstelie (1982), Ireland (1990), and Besley and Coate (1991) individuals can purchase a private sector alternative which allows them to opt out of the public sector, while in Epple and Romano (1996) and Gouveia (1996) they can supplement their public sector allocations. In either case, the emphasis is on substitutability between public and private sector alternatives. In spite of its theoretical importance, there is almost no previous empirical evidence on whether such substitutions appear to occur empirically. A recent exception is Cutler and Gruber (1996) who study how medicaid provision, which varies across states in the US, affects the decision by low income individuals to insure. They find evidence of `crowding out', in which government alternatives diminish the incentive of low income individuals to purchase private insurance. Such findings are consonant with ours even though the institutional circumstances are very different.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section discusses some background information relevant to understanding the health care system in the UK. Section 3then builds a simple model of the willingness to pay for private insurance in the UK system, making precise the link between public sector quality and the decision to insure. Section 4establishes the framework for the empirical work and develops the results. Section 5concludes.

Section snippets

The NHS

The NHS has been the principal source of medical care for the vast majority of British residents since its inception in 1948. It enjoys widespread political support, with its financing being highly politicized. Despite suspicions that the former Conservative government lacked a commitment to the NHS, real expenditure has been growing over the last 15 years.

Willingness to pay for private health insurance

The model developed here is based on the approach to public provision of private goods in Besley and Coate (1991). Consider an individual who faces a probability θ∈[0,1] of being sick. To be cured of the sickness requires that he purchase one unit of medical care (a `treatment'). We suppose that treatments are available in varying quality levels, denoted by q∈[q,q̄]. These differences in quality could reflect the treatment of patients during care, e.g. length of time waiting for treatment or

Empirical specification and results

We now develop an empirical specification. This is done in two stages. We begin with a simple Probit model which does not differentiate between sources of health insurance. We then turn to a two equation model, where the primary focus is on individual purchases of private health insurance plans for those who have not obtained insurance through an employer.

Discussion

Our results suppose that individuals form some estimate of public sector quality when making their private insurance decision. There are two main channels through which this could work. First, media reports and political debate have focused on this indicator of NHS quality, and it is possible that individuals pick up a local sense of the conditions using this as a barometer. Second, it is likely that individuals do rely on more informed parties such as their General Practitioner in making their

Acknowledgements

This paper draws on research funded by the Economic and Social Research Council under the Realising Our Potential Awards (ROPA) scheme (grant No. R022250032) and the Economic Beliefs and Behaviour Programme (grant No. L122521004). We are grateful to Social and Community Planning Research and the ESRC Data Archive for access to the British Social Attitudes survey data. We have received helpful comments and advice from Richard Blundell, Ian Crawford, Howard Glennerster, Roger Gordon, Jonathan

References (20)

  • N. Ireland

    The mix of social and private provision of goods and services

    Journal of Public Economics

    (1990)
  • C. Propper

    Constrained choice sets in the UK demand for private medical insurance

    Journal of Public Economics

    (1993)
  • J.E. Stiglitz

    The demand for education in public and private school systems

    Journal of Public Economics

    (1974)
  • Y. Barzel

    A theory of rationing by waiting

    Journal of Law and Economics

    (1974)
  • T. Besley et al.

    Public provision of private goods and the redistribution of income

    American Economic Review

    (1991)
  • T. Besley et al.

    Alternative systems of health care provision

    Economic Policy

    (1994)
  • Besley, T., Hall, J., Preston, I., 1996. Private health insurance and the state of the NHS. IFS Commentary No. 52,...
  • Bosanquet, N., 1988. An ailing state of National Health. In: Jowell, R., Brook, L., Taylor, B. (Eds), British Social...
  • D. Cutler et al.

    Does public insurance crowd out private insurance?

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1996)
  • R. Deacon et al.

    Rationing by waiting and the value of time: evidence from a natural experiment

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1985)
There are more references available in the full text version of this article.

Cited by (158)

  • Private health insurance consumption and public health-care provision in OECD countries: Impact of culture, finance, and the pandemic

    2023, North American Journal of Economics and Finance
    Citation Excerpt :

    These studies have revealed that an increase in public health spending may reduce spending on PHI. Besley et al. (1999) and Bíró and Hellowell (2016) have confirmed that the long waiting lists for national health service treatment in the United Kingdom prompts people to increase their spending on PHI. In addition, Besley et al. (1999) and Sagan and Thomson (2016) have reported that individuals purchase PHI for the following reasons: (1) to cover gaps in publicly financed health coverage, (2) to have the freedom to choose their own health-care provider, (3) to benefit from faster access to treatment, (4) to obtain the specific treatment they require, and (5) to simplify their medical payments.

View all citing articles on Scopus
View full text