Land relations under unbearable stress: Rwanda caught in the Malthusian trap

https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2681(97)00045-0Get rights and content

Abstract

This paper reports the findings of an in-depth case study of a highly densely populated area in northwest Rwanda which has been conducted during the period 1988–1993. It demonstrates that acute competition for land in a context characterized by too slow expansion of non-agricultural income opportunities has resulted in increasingly unequal land distribution and rapid processes of land dispossession through both operation of the (illegal) land market and evolution of indigenous tenure arrangements. It is also shown that pervasive incidence of land disputes and the threat of landlessness have led to rising tensions in social relations and even within the core of family life, thus paving the way for evermore overt expressions of disharmony and violence. A connection between these ominous conditions and the civil war that broke out in 1994 is established.

Introduction

Under the influence of Boserup's seminal work, an evolutionary theory of land rights has gained increasing currency among development scholars (see Platteau, 1996for a recent survey). According to this theory, there exists an evolutionary path along which new techniques and institutional arrangements are adopted by farmers living in areas subject to growing pressure on available lands as a result of population growth and/or increasing commercialization of agriculture. These new techniques or land use patterns as well as the newly emerging land tenure arrangements are appropriate because they are well adapted to the evolving factor endowments in the agricultural sector. On the one hand, the new agricultural techniques and land use patterns aim at economizing on the scarce resource and, on the other hand, land rights develop in the direction of increasing individualization, which is precisely what is required by intensification of agricultural production and preservation of soil fertility (since, with more and more complete private property rights, farmers are both more willing and able to invest).

This paper sets out to question the relevance of such an optimistic view in the light of the experience of Rwanda, one of the most densely populated countries of the African continent. It is true that the evidence to be presented undoubtedly confirms the oft-made observation that when pressure on land rises as a result of population growth and growing commercialization of agriculture, indigenous land systems evolve towards increasingly individualized forms of tenure (see, e.g. Noronha, 1985, Downs and Reyna, 1988, Migot-Adholla et al., 1991, Platteau, 1992, Bassett and Crummey, 1993, Peters, 1994)1. Yet, emphasis is simultaneously put on the serious strains and stresses that are bound to occur (1) when there are rising inequalities in landholding and land access as a result of the twin processes of individualization and marketization of land rights; (2) when the productivity effects following from the emergence of de facto private property rights are too weak to stave off the operation of diminishing returns as labour intensity of agriculture increases and to maintain output per capita in the long run; and (3) when off-farm employment tends to exacerbate, rather than mitigate, growing economic (land access) inequities within the rural sector.

On the basis of highly suggestive empirical material, the story told below documents how the “Malthusian trap” can result in bitter tensions within families, intra-community hatreds and violence, and serious questioning of the evolving regime of market-allocated, individualized property rights. These adverse effects which corrode the very core of community life are shown to have been at work in the course of events that led to the truly horrifying bloodshed that took place in Rwanda during 1994. In other words, our findings provide a striking echo to Gérard Prunier's comment that “all these people who were about to be killed had land and at times cows. And somebody had to get these lands and those cows after their owners were dead. In a poor and increasingly overpopulated country this was not a negligible incentive” (Prunier, 1995, p. 142).

An important objective pursued in this paper is, therefore, to call into question the dominant view according to which the agricultural sector, thanks to the beneficial operation of virtuous evolutionary forces inducing technological and institutional progress, is able to generate adequate responses to the new challenges arising from rapidly growing land pressure. Also, we hope to help fill up a serious gap in the literature on land tenure in Sub-Saharan Africa since this literature has been excessively focused on productivity issues (more specifically, on the relationship between individualization of land tenure on the one hand, and use of credit, land improvements and yields on the other) while largely ignoring the equity aspects of the inevitable transformation of land rights in regions subject to rapid population growth2. As shall be seen, growing land concentration and rising poverty do not only take place through disequalizing market transfers but also through the gradual erosion of customary social protection following the commoditization of land (when land is acquired through the market, it becomes exempt from customary rules and restraints).

Section snippets

The choice of Rwanda

In order to achieve the above objectives, the paper will highlight how the distribution of land access rights and the social fabric have evolved in a Rwandan village – or, more exactly, a hill

Farm sizes and land fragmentation

Our sample for the year 1993 comprises 87 households out of a total of 124 households living in N (that is, a proportion of 70%) while the size of our 1988 sample is 56 households out of a total of 108 (a proportion of 52%)

An overview

Careful observation of everyday life in N reveals a large incidence of all sorts of conflicts, ranging from land-related disputes to conjugal tensions, non-fulfilment of (implicit) contractual obligations and thefts. Moreover, a good number of these conflicts lead to emotional outbursts of anger and bouts of sheer violence (under the form of destruction of assets, thefts, threats of poisoning and physical assaults with machetes) which official authorities cannot always repress. Generally,

Policy implications

One important lesson from the case study of N is that spontaneous individualization of land rights, unassisted by any process of titling or registration at the state level, can be extremely effective in activating the land market even when land sales do actually violate the law. The fact is worth stressing since in neighbouring Kenya, by contrast, we learn that “Most smallholders, even after registration, do not do the things with their land that registration seeks to empower them to do, such

Acknowledgements

A first field study carried out during the year 1988 and the processing of data collected in 1988 and, later, in 1993 would not have been possible without the financial support of the University of Namur. Also gratefully acknowledged is the support for the second round of the field study (in 1993) that has come from the Musée Royal de l'Afrique Centrale (MRAC) of Tervuren, Belgium, within the framework of a cooperation project between the Institut de Recherche Scientifique et Technique (IRST),

References (72)

  • Barrere, B. et al., 1994. Enquête démographique et de santé, Rwanda 1992, République Rwandaise (Office National de la...
  • Bassett, T.J., Crummey, D.E. (Eds.), 1993. Land in African Agrarian Systems (University of Wisconsin Press, Madison,...
  • Belshaw, C., 1965. Traditional exchange and modern markets (Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs,...
  • T Besley

    Property rights and investment incentives: Theory and evidence from Ghana

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1995)
  • Blarel, B., 1994. Tenure security and agricultural production under land scarcity: The case of Rwanda, In: Bruce, J.W.,...
  • Bourdieu, P., 1980. Le sens pratique (Editions de Minuit,...
  • Brasselle, A.S., Gaspart, F., Platteau, J.P., 1997. The relationship between land tenure security and investment...
  • Bruce, J.W., 1986. Land tenure issues in project design and strategies for agricultural development in Sub-Saharan...
  • Bruce, J.W., 1993. Do indigenous tenure systems constrain agricultural development?, In: Bassett, T.J., Crummey, D.E....
  • Bruce, J.W., Migot-Adholla, S.E. (Eds.), 1994. Searching for Land Tenure Security in Africa (Kendall/Hunt Publishing...
  • de Lame, D., 1996. Une colline entre mille ou le calme avant la tempête – Transformations et blocages du Rwanda rural,...
  • Downs, R.E., Reyna, S.P. (Eds.), 1988. Land and Society in Contemporary Africa (University Press of New England,...
  • Eeckhoudt, L., Gollier, C., 1995. Risk – Evaluation, Management and Sharing (Harvester Wheatsheaf, New York and...
  • Evans-Pritchard, E.E., 1940. The Nuer: A Description of the Modes of Livelihood and Political Institutions of a Nilotic...
  • J Fei et al.

    Growth and family distribution of income by factor components

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1978)
  • Firmin-Sellers, K., 1996. The transformation of property rights in the Gold Coast – An Empirical Analysis Applying...
  • Gasasira, E., 1993. Manuel de droit rwandais: Droit des biens et droit agraire (Bruylant,...
  • Government of Rwanda, 1988, Production agricole en 1986 – tome 1 – Bilan d'autosuffisance alimentaire par commune et...
  • Gregory, C.A., 1982. Gifts and Commodities, (Academic Press, London and New...
  • Harrison, P., 1992. What is going right with African agriculture?, In: Obasanjo, O., d'Orville, H. (Eds.), The...
  • Hesseling, G., 1992. Pratiques foncières à l'ombre du droit – L'application du droit foncier urbain à Ziguinchor,...
  • S.P.S Ho

    Decentralized industrialization and rural development: Evidence from Taiwan

    Economic Development and Cultural Change

    (1979)
  • Lanjouw, P., 1992. Inequality, Poverty and Mobility: The Experience of a North Indian Village, Ph.D. Dissertation...
  • Lawry, S.W., 1993. Transactions in cropland held under customary tenure in Lesotho, In: Bassett, T.J., Crummey, D.E....
  • Le Roy, E., Karsenty, A., Bertrand, A., 1996. La sécurisation foncière en Afrique (Karthala,...
  • Liedholm, C., Kilby, P., 1989. The role of nonfarm activities in the rural economy, In: The balance between industry...
  • Cited by (325)

    • Land reform and rural conflict. Evidence from 1930s Spain

      2023, Explorations in Economic History
    • Persecution, pogroms and genocide: A conceptual framework and new evidence

      2022, Explorations in Economic History
      Citation Excerpt :

      Similarly, most work on persecution in other contexts is concerned with short-run factors. André and Platteau (1998) show that rising competition for land in Rwanda leads to increased social tension and violence. Verpoorten (2012) shows that this “Malthusian pressure on land” (proxied by population density) predicts the intensity of the Rwandan genocide.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text