Review
The behavioral economics of will in recovery from addiction

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.drugalcdep.2006.09.004Get rights and content

Abstract

Behavioral economic studies demonstrate that rewards are discounted proportionally with their delay (hyperbolic discounting). Hyperbolic discounting implies temporary preference for smaller rewards when they are imminent, and this concept has been widely considered by researchers interested in the causes of addictive behavior. Far less consideration has been given to the fact that systematic preference reversal also predicts various self-control phenomena, which may also be analyzed from a behavioral economic perspective.

Here we summarize self-control phenomena predicted by hyperbolic discounting, particularly with application to the field of addiction. Of greatest interest is the phenomenon of choice bundling, an increase in motivation to wait for delayed rewards that can be expected to result from making choices in whole categories. Specifically, when a person's expectations about her own future behavior are conditional upon her current behavior, the value of these expectations is added to the contingencies for the current behavior, resulting in reduced impulsivity. Hyperbolic discounting provides a bottom–up basis for the intuitive learning of choice bundling, the properties of which match common descriptions of willpower. We suggest that the bundling effect can also be discerned in the advice of 12-step programs.

Section snippets

Limitations of rational choice theory

A great deal of research has been done on addictions and their treatment, but the reason why addictions occur in the first place is still unclear. One undeniable element common to addictions is the addict's inability to escape when she wants to, that is, the persistence and frequent alternation of contradictory preferences about her addictive activity. Her inability to make her choices consistent over time is what compels her to seek treatment. Indeed two of the seven defining criteria for

Hyperbolic discounting as a factor in addictive behavior

The immediacy of reward associated with drug use clearly has some importance in understanding why quitting can be difficult. The rewards from drug use are immediate and the adverse consequences tend to be delayed; were the reverse true – if the high from smoking crack did not arrive till weeks later, but the bad feelings associated with all the personal loss came on as soon as blood carried the drug to the brain – it is unlikely there would be problem drug use. As Samual Butler remarked “If the

The self as population

Hyperbolic discounting transforms what has been modeled as a unitary self into a population of competing agents. The elementary agents are no longer individuals, but motivated processes within the individual – call them interests – which compete to be “her” choice on the basis of the shifting values of the rewards on which these interests are based. Allowing for hyperbolic discounting in economic utility functions radically changes behavioral economic modeling in ways that have so far received

Intertemporal bargaining in 12-step recovery

A 12-step treatment for addiction appears to be, at least in some circumstances, more effective than an equivalent amount of either cognitive behavioral therapy or supportive expressive therapy (Crits-Christoph et al., 1999). Interestingly, evidence suggests that the advantage of 12-step treatment (in terms of abstinence rates) over other therapies is most apparent during periods in which particularly high craving is experienced (Weiss et al., 2003). In other words, individuals in 12-step seem

The status of hyperbolic discounting as a factor in addiction and recovery

The theory of hyperbolic discounting implies a need for radical changes in RCT. It has been reasonable for authors to question whether these changes are necessary. This discussion has been ongoing in a number of areas (Ainslie, 2005 and its commentaries), but two suggestions seem important to discuss here: doubt stemming from the great variability of discounting rates in humans, and the possible adequacy of classical conditioning as an alternative mechanism for the pathogenesis and treatment of

Can intertemporal bargaining be studied empirically?

It might be contended that intertemporal bargaining does not fit the framework of empirical science. As discussed above, the fundamental building block of the model is the recursive interplay between current preference and expectation of future behavior. What are the prospects of doing quantitative behavioral economic modeling of a hypothesized system with a recursive feedback loop between components that are not directly measurable?

With varying degrees of success, we and others, have looked

Acknowledgement

Financial support for this work was provided by NIDA DAK01515 (JM).

References (96)

  • R. Thaler

    Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency

    Econ. Lett.

    (1981)
  • M. van der Pol et al.

    Estimating time preferences for health using discrete choice experiments

    Soc. Sci. Med.

    (2001)
  • T. Ward et al.

    The abstinence violation effect in child molesters

    Behav. Res. Ther.

    (1994)
  • G. Ainslie

    Specious reward: a behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulse control

    Psychol. Bull.

    (1975)
  • G. Ainslie

    Freud and picoeconomics

    Behaviorism

    (1989)
  • G. Ainslie

    Picoeconomics: The Strategic Interaction of Successive Motivational States Within the Person

    (1992)
  • G. Ainslie

    Breakdown of Will

    (2001)
  • G. Ainslie

    Gods are more flexible than resolutions

    Behav. Brain Sci.

    (2004)
  • G. Ainslie

    Precis of breakdown of will

    Behav. Brain. Sci.

    (2005)
  • G. Ainslie
  • G. Ainslie et al.
  • G. Ainslie et al.
  • G. Ainslie et al.

    Building blocks of self-control: increased tolerance for delay with bundled rewards

    J. Exp. Anal. Behav.

    (2003)
  • Aristotle

    The Complete Works of Aristotle

    (1984)
  • A. Bain

    Emotions and the Will

    (1859)
  • W.K. Bickel et al.

    Toward a behavioral economic understanding of drug dependence: delay discounting processes

    Addiction

    (2001)
  • W.K. Bickel et al.

    Impulsivity and cigarette smoking: delay discounting in current, never, and ex-smokers

    Psychopharmacology

    (1999)
  • T. Bien et al.

    Mindful Recovery: A Spiritual Path to Healing from Addiction

    (2002)
  • Bodner, R., Prelec, D., 2001. In: Brocas, I., Carillo, J.D. (Eds.), Collected Essays in Psychology and Economics....
  • P. Bohm

    Time preference and preference reversal among experienced subjects: the effects of real payments

    Econ. J.

    (1994)
  • R. Boudon

    The “rational choice model:” a particular case of the “cognitive model”

    Rational. Soc.

    (1996)
  • M. Bratman

    Faces of Intention: Selected Essays on Intention and Agency

    (1999)
  • C.F. Camerer
  • G.B. Chapman

    Temporal discounting and utility for health and money

    J. Exp. Psychol. Learn. Mem. Cogn.

    (1996)
  • G.B. Chapman

    Preferences for improving and declining sequences of health outcomes

    J. Behav. Decis. Making

    (2000)
  • G.B. Chapman et al.

    Value for the future and preventive health behavior

    J. Exp. Psychol. Appl.

    (2001)
  • H. Chesson et al.

    The heterogeneity of time-risk tradeoffs

    J. Behav. Decis. Making

    (2000)
  • R.L. Collins et al.

    Restraint and attributions: evidence of the abstinence violation effect in alcohol consumption

    Cogn. Ther. Res.

    (1991)
  • C.A. Conklin et al.

    Applying extinction research and theory to cue-exposure addiction treatments

    Addiction

    (2002)
  • J. Cook et al.

    Choice of delay of inevitable shock

    J. Abnorm. Soc. Psychol.

    (1964)
  • J.P. Crean et al.

    Reward discounting as a measure of impulsive behavior in a psychiatric outpatient population

    Exp. Clin. Psychopharmacol.

    (2000)
  • P. Crits-Christoph et al.

    Psychosocial treatments for cocaine dependence: National Institute on Drug Abuse Collaborative Cocaine Treatment Study

    Arch. Gen. Psychiatry

    (1999)
  • R. Dar et al.

    Craving to smoke in orthodox Jewish smokers who abstain on the Sabbath: a comparison to a baseline and a forced abstinence workday

    Psychopharmacology (Berl.)

    (2005)
  • J. Elster
  • Gintis, H. A framework for the unification of the behavioral sciences. Behav. Brain Sci., in...
  • P.W. Glimcher et al.
  • L. Green et al.

    A discounting framework for choice with delayed and probabilistic rewards

    Psychol. Bull.

    (2004)
  • L. Green et al.

    Temporal discounting when the choice is between two delayed rewards

    J. Exp. Psychol. Learn. Mem. Cogn.

    (2005)
  • Cited by (50)

    • On the discounting of cannabis and money: Sensitivity to magnitude vs. delay

      2020, Drug and Alcohol Dependence
      Citation Excerpt :

      Over the past several decades, research on delay discounting has robustly informed our understanding of substance use and misuse (Bickel et al., 2011a, 2014; Monterosso and Ainslie, 2007).

    • A brief review of choice bundling: A strategy to reduce delay discounting and bolster self-control

      2020, Addictive Behaviors Reports
      Citation Excerpt :

      An additive process, choice bundling extends the decision maker’s temporal horizon, pushing them to weigh the sum of multiple short-term rewards against the sum of multiple long-term consequences. The summation of a series of hyperbolic discounting curves converges to an exponential one; thus, choice bundling theoretically works to bolster self-control by removing the allure of preference reversal (Ainslie & Monterosso, 2007). Specifically, bundling has been proposed to reduce impulsive choice via two pathways: (1) increasing the likelihood that an individual will accurately take into account all of the future benefits and consequences, and (2) increasing an individual’s expectancy that they will continue to make non-impulsive choices to the extent that they view their first choice as a “test case” for the entire bundling period (Ainslie, 2013).

    • Impulsive mechanisms influencing relapse in alcohol drinking

      2018, Medical Hypotheses
      Citation Excerpt :

      The consideration of variables that reduce discount rate may contribute to longer periods of abstinence. For example, pre-commitment mechanisms [28] may strengthen the preference for delayed consequences over immediate ones. Presenting choice situations involving a sequence of choices (e.g. five consecutive choices) may make a current choice predictive of future choices and consequently prevent alcohol consumption [29,30].

    • Neural underpinnings of maladaptive decision-making in addictions

      2018, Pharmacology Biochemistry and Behavior
    • The neuropsychology of decision-making: A view from the frontal lobes

      2017, Decision Neuroscience: An Integrative Perspective
    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text